A smile never increases in price or decreases in value.
Supply & Demand II
In light of the popularity of my blog called Simple Economics (click to read)I decided to take economics a bit farther and introduce you to the supply and demand curves. We discussed the basic principles of the two curves Monday. If you didn’t read it, please scroll down and read that one before proceeding with this.
lug.wsu.edu
Today, we’re going to discuss what happens when prices rise above or decline below this point of stability. Although this is just the raw basics, hopefully this will make some sense out of the world of economics for you.
As we discussed Monday, the point where the two curves cross, which we have labeled “Equilibrium,” is the point at which the number of units of product or service are exactly equal to the number the public is willing and able to buy. In a perfect world, there would be no reason for prices to go up or down from that point, because supply and demand are in balance. In our imperfect world, however, the prices tend not to be that stable.
If the price goes up, suppliers are willing to produce more units—either from the expansion of existing producers or from additional companies getting into that market as it becomes more lucrative. However, fewer people are both willing and able to purchase at that higher price.
Think about yourself for a moment. With most items, you are both willing and able to buy at a certain price, but if the price starts rising you begin to lose interest in purchasing. Let’s think of a couple of products with totally different reactions to this.
You enjoy taking your family out to dinner after church on Sundays. As long as the price remains reasonable, you continue to do so, but as the price goes up, this is an item you can pretty easily do without, so you just start going home to eat after church. In a case like that, the demand curve would be somewhat flatter than that in our example, because the price doesn’t have to go up too much before you change your habit.
In general, restaurant employee don’t have to be highly skilled, and expanding the supply is not all that difficult, nor does it involve years of building new factories or whatever. As the price goes up, supply can expand pretty rapidly, so the supply curve is also relatively flatter than that in the diagram.
Now think about gasoline. The summer of 2008 the price of a gallon of unleaded gasoline shot up from under $3.00 a gallon to over $4.00 a gallon. Did you sell your car and buy a horse? No. You need your car, so you just paid the higher prices. You may have exercised more restraint in how much you drove, but you didn’t quit driving. As the price increased, demand waned somewhat, but it still remained strong.
Likewise, increasing the price doesn’t immediately cause a tremendous increase in the supply of gasoline. There may be a marginal capacity available to increase the supply, but for real increases, we need years to find new fields, drill new wells, and build new refineries. Both the supply and demand curves for gasoline would be much more nearly vertical than the examples in our diagram.
Make sense so far? I hope so.
Okay, if the price increases, demand will decrease—even for gasoline—and supply will increase. What effect does that have?
It means suppliers can’t sell all they are producing. They begin having to store the excess, which is a costly process, and they come to realize they could sell more by lowering the prices.
By the same token, if prices drop too low, some producers will cut or curtail their production, while buyers want to purchase more. Then a bidding war will drive the price back up toward equilibrium.
So we see that, without any action on the part of Ralph Nadir or Karl Marx or the federal government, the law of supply and demand inevitably forces prices back toward equilibrium. This is the beauty of the free enterprise system. Left to its own devices, it is automatically self-correcting.
This discussion has been oversimplified to make the principles understandable. It is more or less the way things would work if there were no international trade and no interference from the government, labor unions, environmental activists or other outside forces.
In reality, international trade has a major impact on all of this, because costs of production are so much lower in other countries that their equilibrium points are much lower than ours. Some of the demand that would normally support prices here is filled by foreign producers, removing that demand from our domestic companies and forcing lower prices here. This is largely why General Motors, Ford and Chrysler struggle so much and account for so much smaller parts of our auto sales than they used to.
Taxes and environmental regulations add to the costs of domestic companies. To understand the effect of these things, imagine the curves in the diagram above, and imagine what would happen if you arbitrarily moved the blue supply curve higher. I don’t mean move to a higher point on the curve—I mean move the curve itself higher. The equilibrium point would move upward and to the left to find where the two arcs cross, cutting back on the demand without adding a penny to the net coffers of the producers.
Labor unions, industrial safety regulations and other outside factors also add to the prices, moving the supply curve higher without adding to the companies’ revenues. This is not an argument for unsafe industrial practices or other such things. I just point out the effect that these external influences have on our supply and demand and prices.
If you believe in high taxes or strong labor unions or crushing environmental regulations, that is your right. But please understand the cost to you and to our country every time we add to any of these pressures. We increase our own cost of living and reduce the amount of goods and services available with each addition. And as companies react to these pressures, more of them move production overseas. They’re not being evil; they’re just reacting to outside pressures brought to bear on them.
David N. Walker is a Christian father and grandfather, a grounded pilot and a near-scratch golfer who had to give up the game because of shoulder problems. A graduate of Duke University, he spent 42 years as a health insurance agent. Most of that career was spent in Texas, but for a few years he traveled many other states. He started writing about 20 years ago, and has six unpublished novels to use as primers on how NOT to write fiction. Since his retirement from insurance a few years ago, he has devoted his time to helping Kristen Lamb start Warrior Writers’ Boot Camp and trying to learn to write a successful novel himself.
Hi David.
This is a good series. Supply and demand applies to so many things, doesn’t it. For example, my bank account is always on the lower left side of P and Q!
Cheers!
LikeLike
But Nigel, that would imply a gap between available money and uses for it. . . .
LikeLike
In my case that means P and Q can’t even see each other, let alone met up occasionally!
LikeLike
Now, Nigel . . . everyone knows that defense contractors are fatcats with money rolling out of their pockets. lol
LikeLike
Thanks, Angela. I agree we need to care for our environment, but we need to base our actions on real science and not something some former Vice President said. We also need to consider the cost to our economy of whatever environmental or other causes we espouse.
LikeLike
Thanks, Ashley. I always wonder if all the “global warming” alarmists remember when the big scare was global cooling about 30 or 40 years ago. We’ve always had cycles. Glad to have a scientist weigh in.
LikeLike
And this is why I was an Art major! Hahaha!
LikeLike
That’s okay, Susie. I can’t draw a triangle.
LikeLike
David, fiscally I am conservative but socially I am democrat. (My husband would say liberal.) I think NAFTA was one of the worst mistakes the US made as we sent many of our unskilled jobs overseas, and -as you pointed out, these effects take time to brew and stew so we can feel them. Now we don’t have jobs for folks who really aren’t scholars and have no business in college.
I feel differently when we toss in the word “environment” as you did in the last paragraph so very casually. We only have one world, and we have to share its resources: water, air. So yeah, I guess I believe in having some pretty stringent regulations in that area because I know without them, many companies will take the low road and become like the dude in the Lorax who mucks everything up, dumping gunk into our water and air, burying waste (a la Love Canal). These environmental travesties take decades to clean. And many of these “disasters” shouldn’t have happened in the first place, if only people followed the rules.
But just like in school, there are always cheaters. And unfortunately sometimes freedoms change because of their abuses. I could reference the Triangle Shirtwaist Fire to discuss Unions, but I know that’s not what you are talking about.
I have really liked this series. A lot.
LikeLike
I agree with you, Renee, that we need to protect our environment, although I’m sure we would disagree on what protections are necessary and what are not. My main point was that each of these things which are not relevant to the actual production and distribution of goods and services adds artificially to the cost, moving the equilibrium point up and reducing both supply and demand, with the net result of shipping jobs overseas where whatever it is can be made more cheaply.
LikeLike